Prime Minister Narendra Modi’s exhortation ‘Make in
India’ would make perfect sense till we realise that by ‘making’ he
means manufacturing. But could it be that his focus on manufacturing may
come a cropper if we do not ensure that agriculture is placed
permanently on a sound footing? The history of the great manufacturing
nations that the PM has been visiting suggests that. So does recent
experience here.
It would, of course, be politically
correct to speak of the importance of agriculture at this point when
farmer suicides have been in the news. Actually, though, the economy has
been signalling for some time that all is not well with the sector.
Note that I say ‘economy’, and am therefore not referring to agriculture
alone. The performance of agriculture has an implication for a
population wider than that contained by it. At least for five years,
food price increases have driven economy-wide inflation.
That
food-price inflation has persisted suggests that a structural factor is
likely at work. The market mechanism can in principle eliminate
inflationary pressure emanating from shortage by encouraging the
expansion of the sector now made attractive by the increased
profitability. That this is not happening with respect to India’s food
sector points to structural impediments in place, ones the market cannot
eliminate.
Food for thought
Food-price
inflation has consequences for more than just economy-wide inflation. It
can even impact the part of the economy close to our PM’s heart,
manufacturing. This is evident from the reports that while inflation is
at a four-month low, the index of industrial production is at a
five-month low.
There is a plausible explanation for
this. Food price inflation can crowd-out household expenditure on
manufactures, leading to declining investment and thus demand for
capital goods. Higher inflation also leads to real exchange-rate
appreciation, rendering exports uncompetitive. So in many ways, a
vibrant manufacturing sector requires a sound agricultural base.
The
agrarian crisis in the country partly reflects the structural element
in the problem of expanding agricultural production. It has two
implications for economic policy.
The first is the
message that if the production conditions are the constraint, then,
trying to tackle the agrarian crisis by raising procurement price — as
has been proposed — is tantamount to no more than feeding inflation.
The
UPA 2 had discovered this fact the hard way. Apart from the fact that
support prices are mostly confined to cereals, and the price rise is
happening elsewhere, producers in India’s non-agricultural sector are
not going to be mere spectators in the reduction in their real income.
They constitute 80 per cent of the economy, and are likely to raise the
price of their outputs to compensate for its reduction.
Now,
not only is the original rise in the procurement price generalised
across the economy, but also it will connect the inflation rate over
time. For, the price would have to be raised again in the next round to
restore parity with non-agricultural prices.
Thus, trying to shift the advantage towards the farmers by raising support prices cannot normally succeed.
To both improve the lot of farmers, and for the rest of the economy to
reap the benefits of such a move, the yield of land must be raised
continuously. This would require non-price interventions. Modi cannot be
ignorant of these as they constitute what must count as governance, and
he had promised to maximise it.
So, what are the
areas within agriculture that require better governance? First and
foremost, there is irrigation. Secondly, there is the issue of land
policy.
Watering land
Expanding irrigation has
been the bugbear of governments in India. While estimates vary, we know
for sure that the share of irrigated land in total cropped area is low.
Increasing this share is vital as assured availability of water can
overcome some of the disadvantages of small farm size.
Some
years ago, the Economic Advisory Council to the PM noted that though
the average holding size in much of East Asia was smaller than that in
India, the share of irrigated land was much higher in the former. This
accounts for the fact that these economies enjoy far greater food
security that India does, and must have some bearing on their being
world-class manufacturing nations.
However, while
the slow growth of irrigated area may be a cause of the tardy expansion
of food production in India, it has less to do with funding than with
governance. In a study published by the RBI in 2008, Ramesh Golait,
Pankaj Kumar and I showed that public expenditure on irrigation and
flood control had gone up by over 100 per cent in real terms since 1991,
with precious little to show for it on the ground. Low spending cannot
account for the glacial spread of irrigation capacity in the country.
To see public expenditure on irrigation fructify, we would need
governance encompassing conception, construction, supply and
maintenance. It is not clear that farmers are part of the process right
now, even as it would be wise to include them, for as potential users
they have a stake in the success of the project.
Politicians
tend to showcase high expenditure on irrigation, and have succeeded in
turning such expenditure into a sacred cow so that querying outcomes is
to be “anti-farmer”.
Land issues
The pressure
of population has led to fragmentation of many farms to a level below
economic size. Sizeable investment is now made difficult.
Further,
at low output levels, any adverse fluctuation drives the farmer into
poverty and debt, from which recovery is impossible without assistance.
There
is a strong case for the prevention of further fragmentation of land by
appropriate legislation. At the same time, legislation must also allow
for tenancy, which is illegal in many parts of India.
In
fact, the State should facilitate tenancy on reasonable terms so that
necessary yield increase is not held back due to the uneconomic size of
land.
Another issue is the alienation of
agricultural land. There is a strong case for disallowing the conversion
of farmland except in the rarest of rare cases. In fact, the proposed
Social Impact Assessment is perhaps too narrowly conceived. It tends to
privilege the rights of those deriving a livelihood from the land in
question.
Actually, there is the question of the
greater common good, from which point of view food security for the
nation as a whole emerges as salient. Given the imponderables,
especially due to climate change and the fact that grain production per
capita is far lower here than in the developed world, an embargo on
conversion, whether undertaken by government or owners, makes much
sense.
While there is no need for Modi to put his
enthusiasm for manufacturing on hold, he should seriously and urgently
address the long-term prospects for our agriculture.
The writer is professor of economics at Ashoka University
No comments:
Post a Comment