Lack of knowledge about the real value of the ecosystem comes in the way of markets finding right prices
Environmental markets are being developed worldwide, on the faith that they will help solve environmental degradation.
Two
major factors have driven this enthusiasm in the developed world:
conscious national environmental policy movements toward market-based
instruments, and rising demand for environmental goods and services.
Developing nations have also geared up towards this direction.
The
reasons for setting up markets are many. First, markets help discover
the right price for the environmental resource and aid their allocation
and distribution, and offer means of achieving social optimality in
consumption and production. Second, markets help raise funds for
sustainable development financing.
Third, market
institutions are supposed to make the common man understand the value of
services that the ecosystem provides to the economy as a whole, the
incidence of economic activity on the ecosystem and its repercussions on
life. Fourth, as scarcity of ecosystem services comes to the fore, the
roles of creating markets and market values become important, as
government instruments fail.
Fifth, markets work well at providing rewards and encouraging resource managers to properly manage natural resources.
When
one looks at the value chain of marketed commodities, one realises
goods extracted from ecosystems have long been traded in markets. The
services provided by ecosystems have been used for just as long, but
have remained beyond markets and largely un-priced.
Resources
with poorly defined or undefined property rights (including forests,
water, or grasslands), if not regulated in their use, can be accessed by
all and used until exhaustion. But just as in any market, an emerging
scarcity can make them tradable.
Reality checks
So
the question arises: why do environmental markets fail so often? The
most recent instance includes the emergence and failure of carbon
markets. Despite the initial successes of environmental markets, some
quarters have criticised them for lacking even basic safeguards against
fraud, and not really resulting in emissions reductions. The overarching
objective of environmental protection depends on whether the markets
are really helping the realisation of efficient prices. Ideally, the
price of a commodity in a market should reflect its scarcity value.
In
theory, the market interaction between the demand and supply forces
leads to equilibrium prices. There is an important assumption here. This
is about the consumer being aware of the “utility” of the commodity.
The
situation is, however, a bit difficult for environment or ecosystem as a
commodity. An efficient market price should ideally reflect the
scarcity value of a resource. Under perfect market conditions, prices
become equal to the scarcity value. For the environmental market,
information is the missing element.
So far, even
ecological scientists have failed to decipher the range of ecosystem
services provided by nature. There is clear lack of knowledge among the
public about what will be the entire range of effects from
trans-boundary air or water pollution. Here, it is difficult for market
prices to reflect the true scarcity value.
A matter of choice
It
has been argued in some quarters that during the recent financial
meltdown, carbon credit prices or more precisely Certified Emission
Reduction (CER) prices diminished, and that is precisely because the
demand for CER, as a commodity in the consumer’s utility bundle, fell.
This
is because consumers preferred other commodities to CERs. Does that
mean that the value of environmental damage has diminished? Of course
not.
Pollution keeps on doing the same damage during a
recession, as it does during prosperous times. Mangroves provide the
same ecosystem benefits that get translated into our economic welfare
function during recession, as during a boom.
This
means there is a clear divorce between prices and value when it comes to
environment. Buyers of environmental services are only aware of a
minuscule portion of the entire range of services that the ecosystem can
offer. It is only this minuscule portion that enters their utility
bundle and gets realised in market prices.
Let us now
look at the supply side. Ecosystem services of nature are independent
of the environmental market. Nature will continue with its provision of
ecosystem goods and services of gas regulation, waste treatment, climate
control, biological control, water regulation, pollination, food
production, soil formation, nutrient cycling and other functions, unless
disturbed by extreme anthropogenic forces or external stimuli.
This
makes prices essentially demand-determined. Unfortunately, the entire
problem is with the demand function of environmental services. No doubt,
the crucial problem here lies with knowledge. In sum, unless there is
adequate information about the environment and ecosystem, it is not
possible for markets to discover right prices.
The writer is Acting President, Indian Society for Ecological Economics
No comments:
Post a Comment