MA Oommen
Admittedly, economics is a social science engaged in the ‘ordinary business of life’. It is the only social science that attracts a Nobel-like award —the Sveriges Risbank Prize in economic sciences in memory of Alfred Nobel’ instituted by the central bank of Sweden from 1969 onwards. The award is given by the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences according to the same principles and procedures as for the prestigious Nobel prizes that have been awarded since 1901. To be sure, the knowledge economic ‘science’ creates must not be sophistries, but something relevant and useful to humanity.
Admittedly, economics is a social science engaged in the ‘ordinary business of life’. It is the only social science that attracts a Nobel-like award —the Sveriges Risbank Prize in economic sciences in memory of Alfred Nobel’ instituted by the central bank of Sweden from 1969 onwards. The award is given by the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences according to the same principles and procedures as for the prestigious Nobel prizes that have been awarded since 1901. To be sure, the knowledge economic ‘science’ creates must not be sophistries, but something relevant and useful to humanity.
People
pursue any scientific study “to learn something about the riddle of the
world in which we live and the riddle of man’s knowledge of that
world”, as the great British philosopher of natural and social science,
Sir Karl Popper, puts it.
Know the world
The
basic purpose of the scientific universe — being the project of
understanding the riddle of the world, the portrayal of market system by
mainstream economics as immutable, inescapable and natural, while it
helps to safeguard any effort to subvert it — turns out to be an
epistemological incongruity. Copernicus and Galileo proved to the world
despite severe odds on the basis of logic, mathematics and facts that
the received belief systems were utterly wrong. Since economics has a
mission in building useful knowledge for the benefit of society, the
persistent pursuit of the discipline to create sophistries to appear
‘scientific’ needs to be continuously interrogated.
During
the latter part of the 1970s, I examined economics syllabi of 26 major
universities in India and found that they were dominated by neoclassical
economics with Marxian epistemology being kept out as poison and
propaganda and even subjects such as economic history treated as
redundant.
This is true of several universities in
other parts of the world today. I wonder why critical scholars are not
making it a social issue. It is illogical to dismiss alternate schools
of thought as irrelevant. There is a pertinent need to re-articulate
economics teaching by bringing together diverse streams of thought which
can challenge the hegemony of market-centered economics.
This
is precisely what you miss when you uphold competitive pricing based on
self-interest of buyers and sellers as logical as Euclid’s geometry as
underscored by Harvard Professors such as Paul Samuleson and Gregory
Mankiw. Interestingly, economics does not have a theory of distribution
and proceeds as if the word exploitation is irrelevant for the
discipline. So long as wage is the price of labour and all factors of
production (land, entrepreneurship, capital, etc.) are compensated
according to their marginal product, exploitation is not raised as an
issue to be considered. Several relevant policy issues are ruled out in
this manner.
Wrong numbers
It is instructive to recall what Kaushik Basu, former economic advisor to the Government of India admitted in his Beyond Invisible Hand
(2010): “The free market proposition is a powerful intellectual
achievement and one of great aesthetic appeal, but its rampant misuse
has had huge implications for the world in particular in the way we
craft policy, think about globalisation and dismiss dissent”.
Continuing
to pursue “powerful intellectual achievements” and “aesthetic appeal”
is a serious limitation in developing a discipline that is basically
policy-oriented. Although 77 professors in economics have become Nobel
laureates, many of them won their awards for mathematical formulations.
True, there are conspicuous exceptions such as Gunnar Myrdal, Amartya
Sen and a few others. John Nash, a great mathematician shared Nobel
prize in 1994 with two other mathematicians “for their pioneering
analysis of equilibrium in the theory of non-cooperative games”.
Kenneth
Arrow (Nobel in 1972) and Gerard Debreu (Nobel in 1983) are honoured
for their contribution to the application of the mathematical theory of
convex sets to the general equilibrium theory.
The very first chapter of Debreu’s Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium
is captioned ‘Mathematics’. My simple question is: can physics
(economics has borrowed heavily terms from physics evidently to appear
scientific) or for that matter any other science where quantitative
calculations are involved start like this and then earn a Nobel prize?
Not
only that, the rigorous assumptions and deductive methods on which
several economic theories are based are not falsifiable. As per the
“falsifiability criterion” of Popper a scientist seeks to discover an
observed exception to his/her postulated rule. Freudian psychoanalysis
for example is not an empirical science because of its failure to adhere
to the principle of falsifiability.
What Robert
Solow (Nobel in 1987) observed recently (2014) while probing ‘inside the
minds of 12 Nobel laureates’ is worth citing: “The fundamental goal of
economics as a discipline is to bring organized reason and systematic
observation to bear on both large and small economic problems (and to
have some intellectual fun on the way)”.
Losing focus
I
wonder how can the creation of ‘intellectual fun’ and intellectual game
be the vocation of a social science. To be sure, the knowledge that you
produce and the intellectual and empirical basis that you build must be
useful to human beings.
Thomas Piketty, whose
proficiency in mathematics is well acknowledged, reminds his fellow
economists in his famous book Capital in the twenty-first century
(2014): “To put it bluntly, the discipline of economics has yet to get
over its childish passion for mathematics and for purely theoretical and
often highly ideological speculation, at the expense of historical
research and collaboration with the other social sciences. Economists
are all too often preoccupied with petty mathematical problems of
interest only to themselves. This obsession with mathematics is an easy
way of acquiring the appearance of scientificity without having to
answer the far more complex questions posed by the world we live in”.
Economics
is a cipher if it ceases to be a human science. While efficient
allocation of resources is important, one cannot ignore the question:
‘efficiency for whom and for what’? Robert Fogel (Nobel laureate in
1993) along with Stanley Engerman (see their Time on the Cross), legitimises Negro slavery on the basis of efficiency.
Modern
economics as a discipline is the outcome of industrial capitalism. But
we cannot forget that economic activities originated from the pursuit of
human beings for food, shelter, clothing and other necessities of life.
With the shift of emphasis from creating useful things for society to
producing commodities in exchange for profit the discipline has lost its
innate character as a human science. Education is the practice of
freedom and all social sciences, especially economics have a key role to
critically engage in the transformation of the society where people
live.
(The writer is an honorary fellow at CDS, Thiruvananthapuram)
No comments:
Post a Comment